EFX implies PROPm

Dependencies:

  1. Fair division
  2. EFX
  3. PROPm
  4. Subadditive and superadditive set functions
  5. Additive set function
  6. PROP-unsat implies someone is superPROP

Let $([n], [m], V, w)$ be a fair division instance for indivisible items (where each agent $i$ has entitlement $w_i$). If an allocation $A$ is EFx-fair to agent $i$, then it is also PROPm-fair to agent $i$ if one of these conditions is satisfied:

  1. $v_i$ is subadditive and the items are chores to agent $i$.
  2. $v_i$ is additive, $w_i ≤ w_j$ for all $j \in [n] \setminus \{i\}$, and $v_i(A_i) ≥ 0$.
  3. $v_i$ is additive and $n=2$.

Proof

Suppose agent $i$ is EFx-satisfied but not PROPm-satisfied by allocation $A$. Then for some agent $\jhat \in [n] \setminus \{i\}$, we have \[ \frac{v_i(A_i)}{w_i} < v_i([m]) < \frac{v_i(A_{\jhat})}{w_{\jhat}}. \]

Since $i$ doesn't EFx-envy $\jhat$, for all $S \subseteq A_i$ such that $v_i(S \mid A_i \setminus S) < 0$, we get \[ \frac{v_i(A_i \setminus S)}{w_i} ≥ \frac{v_i(A_{\jhat})}{w_{\jhat}} > v_i([m]). \] Hence, condition 2 (chores condition) of PROPm is satisfied. If all items are chores, then condition 1 (goods condition) of PROPm is also satisfied.

Let $v_i$ be additive. Since condition 1 (goods condition) of PROPm is not satisfied, we get that $T \neq \emptyset$ and $v_i(A_i) + \max(T) ≤ w_iv_i([m])$.

For all $j \in T$, we get \begin{align} \frac{v_i(A_i)}{w_i} &≥ \frac{\max(\{v_i(A_j \setminus S): S \subseteq A_j \textrm{ and } v_i(S \mid A_i) > 0\})}{w_j} \tag{$i$ doesn't EFX-envy $j$} \\ &= \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\min(\{v_i(S): S \subseteq A_j \textrm{ and } v_i(S) > 0\})}{w_j} \\ &= \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\tau_j}{w_j} ≥ \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\max(T)}{w_j}. \tag{(1)} \end{align}

Special case 1: $w_i ≤ w_j$ for all $j \in [n] \setminus \{i\}$, and $v_i(A_i) ≥ 0$.

Let $J \defeq \{j \in [n] \setminus \{i\}: \tau_j > 0\}$. For all $j \in J$, we get \[ \frac{v_i(A_i) + \max(T)}{w_i} ≥ \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\max(T)}{w_j} + \frac{\max(T)}{w_i} \ge \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j}. \]

For all $j \in [n] \setminus (J \cup \{i\})$, we have $\tau_j = 0$, so $v_i(A_j) ≤ 0$. Hence, \[ \frac{v_i(A_i)}{w_i} ≥ 0 ≥ \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j}. \] Therefore, \[ v([m]) = \sum_{j=1}^n w_j\left(\frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j}\right) < \sum_{j=1}^n w_j\left(\frac{v_i(A_i) + \max(T)}{w_i}\right) = \frac{v_i(A_i) + \max(T)}{w_i}. \] Hence, condition 1 of PROPm is satisfied, which is a contradiction. Hence, it's impossible for $i$ to be EFX-satisfied by $A$ but not PROPm-satisfied by $A$.

Special case 2: $n=2$

Let the two agents be $i$ and $j$. Since $T \neq \emptyset$, we have $\max(T) = \tau_j > 0$. Since $i$ is not PROPm-satisfied by $A$, we get \begin{align} & v_i(A_i) + \tau_j ≤ w_iv_i([m]) = w_iv_i(A_i) + w_iv_i(A_j) \\ &\implies w_jv_i(A_i) + \tau_j ≤ w_iv_i(A_j) \\ &\implies \frac{v_i(A_i)}{w_i} ≤ \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\tau_j}{w_iw_j} ≤ \frac{v_i(A_j)}{w_j} - \frac{\tau_j}{w_j}. \end{align} Combining this with equation (1) gives us $\tau_j = 0$, which is a contradiction. Hence, it's impossible for $i$ to be EFX-satisfied by $A$ but not PROPm-satisfied by $A$.

Dependency for: None

Info:

Transitive dependencies:

  1. /sets-and-relations/countable-set
  2. σ-algebra
  3. Set function
  4. Fair division
  5. Proportional allocation
  6. Envy-freeness
  7. Additive set function
  8. Subadditive and superadditive set functions
  9. PROP-unsat implies someone is superPROP
  10. Submodular function
  11. PROPx
  12. PROPm
  13. EFX