PROPm implies PROP1

Dependencies:

  1. Fair division
  2. PROPm
  3. PROP1
  4. Submodular function
  5. Residual of submodular function is submodular
  6. Submodularity implies subadditivity, supermodularity implies superadditivity

Let $([n], [m], V, w)$ be a fair division instance for indivisible items (where each agent $i$ has entitlement $w_i$). If an allocation $A$ is PROPm-fair to agent $i$, then it is also PROP1-fair to agent $i$ if one of these conditions is satisfied:

Proof

Suppose allocation $A$ is PROPm-fair to $i$ but not PROP1-fair to $i$. Then

  1. $v_i(A_i) < w_iv_i([m])$ (by PROP1 unfairness).
  2. $v_i(A_i \setminus \{c\}) ≤ w_iv_i([m])$ for all $c \in A_i$ (by PROP1 unfairness).
  3. $v_i(A_i \cup \{g\}) ≤ w_iv_i([m])$ for all $g \in [m] \setminus A_i$ (by PROP1 unfairness).
  4. $v_i(A_i \setminus \{c\}) > w_iv_i([m])$ for all $c \in A_i$ such that $v_i(c \mid A_i \setminus \{c\}) < 0$ (by PROPm fairness).
  5. $T = \emptyset$ or $v_i(A_i) + \max(T) > w_iv_i([m])$ (by PROPm fairness).

By 2 and 4, we get $v_i(c \mid A_i \setminus \{c\}) ≥ 0$ for all $c \in A_i$. If $v_i$ is doubly-monotone and $v_i(c \mid \cdot) < 0$ for every chore $c$, then $A_i$ only contains goods. Hence, $v_i(A_i) ≥ 0$. Now suppose $v_i$ is submodular. Let $A_i = \{g_1, \ldots, g_k\}$. Then \[ v_i(A_i) = \sum_{j=1}^k v_i(g_j \mid \{g_1, \ldots, g_{j-1}\}) ≥ v_i(g_j \mid A_i \setminus \{g_j\}) ≥ 0. \] Hence, $v_i(A_i) ≥ 0$ for both conditions.

Suppose $T = \emptyset$. Then $\tau_j = 0$ for all $j \in [n] \setminus \{i\}$. Hence, for all $j \in [n] \setminus \{i\}$ and for all $S \subseteq A_j$, we have $v_i(S \mid A_i) ≤ 0$. If $v_i$ is doubly monotone and $v_i(g \mid \cdot) > 0$ for each good $g$, then $[m] \setminus A_i$ contains only chores. Hence, $v_i([m] \setminus A_i \mid A_i) ≤ 0$. If $v_i$ is submodular, then $v_i(\cdot \mid A_i)$ is subadditive, so $v_i([m] \setminus A_i \mid A_i) ≤ \sum_{j≠i} v_i(A_j \mid A_i) ≤ 0$. Hence, $v_i(A_i) ≥ v_i([m])$. If $v_i([m]) ≤ 0$, then $v_i(A_i) ≥ 0 ≥ w_iv_i([m])$, which contradicts 1. If $v_i([m]) ≥ 0$, then $v_i(A_i) ≥ v_i([m]) ≥ w_iv_i([m])$, which contradicts 1. Hence, $T \neq \emptyset$.

Let $\max(T) = \tau_{\jhat} > 0$. By definition of $\tau_{\jhat}$, we get \begin{align} 0 < \tau_{\jhat} &= \min(\{v_i(S \mid A_i) \mid S \subseteq A_{\jhat} \textrm{ and } v_i(S \mid A_i) > 0\}) \\ &\le \min(\{v_i(g \mid A_i) \mid g \in A_{\jhat} \textrm{ and } v_i(g \mid A_i) > 0\}). \end{align}

Case 1: $v_i(g \mid A_i) ≤ 0$ for all $g \in A_{\jhat}$.
If $v_i$ is doubly-monotone and $v_i(g \mid \cdot) > 0$ for every good $g$, we get that $A_{\jhat}$ only has chores, and so $v_i(S \mid A_i) ≤ 0$ for all $S \subseteq A_{\jhat}$. This contradicts the fact that $\tau_{\jhat} > 0$. Now let $v_i$ be submodular. Since $v_i(\cdot \mid A_i)$ is subadditive, for any $S \subseteq A_{\jhat}$, we get $v_i(S \mid A_i) \le \sum_{c \in S} v_i(c \mid A_i) ≤ 0$. This contradicts the fact that $\tau_{\jhat} > 0$.

Case 2: $v_i(\ghat \mid A_i) > 0$ for some $\ghat \in A_{\jhat}$.
Then $\max(T) = \tau_{\jhat} \le v_i(\ghat \mid A_i)$. By 5, we get $w_iv_i([m]) < v_i(A_i) + \max(T) ≤ v_i(A_i \cup \{\ghat\})$. But this contradicts 3.

Hence, it cannot happen that $i$ is PROPm-satisfied by $A$ but not PROP1-satisfied.

Dependency for: None

Info:

Transitive dependencies:

  1. /sets-and-relations/countable-set
  2. /sets-and-relations/de-morgan-laws
  3. σ-algebra
  4. Set function
  5. Fair division
  6. Proportional allocation
  7. PROP1
  8. Subadditive and superadditive set functions
  9. Submodular function
  10. PROPx
  11. PROPm
  12. Submodularity implies subadditivity, supermodularity implies superadditivity
  13. Residual of submodular function is submodular